Friday, October 31, 2008
Journalists: Learn Economics!
Thursday, October 30, 2008
Eat Global, Vote Local
regarded economic theorist --- somehow stumbled upon my blog post
about voting and commented:
> Presumably the probability that the
> decision ends up in court declines in the margin of victory. Thus, by
> voting one reduces the probability of the decision being made by
> courts.
(Oh, and a shout-out to my Stanford homies --- is that what the kids
are saying these days?)
This point is certainly right, so it's not the case that the benefit
of voting is literally zero as I argued below.
To offer my own add-on to his point, suppose that the burden of proof
in a court case is likely to be on on the side that lost the vote
count. So even if I'm in a 5-4 majority that's reviewed by the
courts, my side may have an easier time prevailing in court on account
of my vote.
But I think it's still the case that the pundits are misinterpreting
Florida 2000.
I think they argue that the lesson that from Florida 2000 is that
"Every vote counts because look how close Florida was."
My response to that is that I already knew that vote tallies could be
close --- that's the whole reason I voted in the first place. But
the Florida experience suggests that what REALLY matters is the view
that the courts take of close elections, not the tally in the close
election itself. So my lesson from Florida 2000 is that my vote
matters even less than I thought it did.
Sad, I know.
But the whole reason to revisit this is the following: Think about
the elections where you ARE likely to be pivotal. Those are the ones
where your vote matters most.
And which elections are those?
Local elections.
If you have a vote for a mayor, a city council person, a zoo bond,
whatever... Those are the elections where your vote will matter. Your
vote --- especially if you are voting in Utah --- is really, really,
really unlikely to affect the presidential election. So don't waste
your time getting informed about the McCain vs. Obama tax plans.
Instead, spend your time getting informed about the city council, the
state legislature, the aviary. That's where your vote is likely to
actually matter.
(I'll return to "Eat Global" in an upcoming post, don't worry.)
Wednesday, October 29, 2008
Auctioning Football Seats
Jets to Auction Seats on eBay
This article is a good answer to a question I often get: "How can I price optimally if I don't know what the demand curve is?"
The Jets get to sell these seat licenses once and only once, so it's not possible for them to do pricing experiments to determine the elasticity of demand. So an auction is a good alternative.
This is pretty similar to what Google did with their IPO a few years back. As with the selling of seat licenses, Google gets to sell these shares once and only once. In a typical IPO, a firm will set a price. If the set price is lower than the market clearing price, then the IPO is "oversubscribed." In this case, the underwriter (usually a big investment bank) will determine which of the potential buyers are allowed to buy.
Oversubscribed IPOs have two big problems. First, the firm is selling its shares for less than the market thinks the shares are worth. This means the firm is leaving money on the table. Second, oversubscribed IPOs have the potential for abuse, as investment banks would often allocate the underpriced shares to favored clients.
If the set price is too high, then the issue is undersubscribed, and all heck breaks loose.
Google circumvented all this using an auction. Google asked investors to submit something like a personal demand curve. Investors gave a list of how many shares they were willing to buy at each price.
Example: I'm willing to buy 100 shares if the price is $50 each. If the price is $40 each, then I'll buy 120. If the price is $30, I'll buy 140.
Then Google took the demand curves and said "We have X shares to sell... What's the price at which quantity demanded (given these demand curves) is equal to quantity supplied?" That was then the price that each buyer paid.
Tuesday, October 28, 2008
Article Discussion Assignment
I like this assignment because I always learn something when reading the articles and discussions.
So I thought I'd summarize some of the articles (and the economics underlying) here.
From a group of PMBA students, I got this one:
Health Groups Pushing for Tax Hike on Cigarettes
The plan is to raise Utah's cigarette taxes from 69.5 cents per pack to $2. That's a big increase!
One notable feature of cigarette demand is that it's somewhat inelastic. This means two things. First, the deadweight loss associated with this tax is likely to be small. Second, the cigarette tax is paid mostly by consumers. Because the poor are disproportionately likely to smoke, we might worry about the distributional implications of this tax.
Compare to the tax on gasoline, as we discussed in class. There, supply is inelastic, so again we have small deadweight losses but the tax burden falls primarily on the suppliers.
Tuesday, October 14, 2008
Comparative Advantage
UT and MA?
Why You Shouldn't Vote
Monday, October 13, 2008
Economics and Health
Sunday, October 12, 2008
Politics = Economics (of course...)
Thursday, October 9, 2008
More on Bubbles
The difficulty is that it's hard to predict what the NPV of cash flows will be. Reasonable people can disagree about whether a firm's business model is sound (and therefore will lead to growing cash flows). So it's not always (ever?) clear what a firm's stock price should be.
Another difficulty is that in bubble times people often start arguing that "fundamentals don't matter any more." Example: About eight years ago, a friend told me that NPV of cash flows had nothing to do with demand for stocks. People bought stocks, he argued, because they liked the company and wanted to be associated with it. If true, then investing in Apple is sort of like rooting for the Utah Jazz.
If you're interested in an economist's view on these questions, go read "Irrational Exuberance" by Robert Shiller.
Public Universities (Continued)
Tuesday, October 7, 2008
Public Universities
It's a nice illustration of how changes in opportunity costs lead to changes in behavior. The opportunity cost associated with action A is the value associated with the thing you can't do because you're doing A.
If you're going to school, you can't work (at least not as much). So the total cost of going to school is tuition plus opportunity cost --- that is, tuition plus the money you don't make because you're going to school instead. And people compare this total cost to the benefit of education when making choices. When the economy slows, the opportunity cost of education falls --- and classes fill up.
But the whole issue of state funding for public universities raises a bigger question --- what's the rationale for governmental involvement in education? To remind you how economists view government involvement in markets, the case for governmental involvement usually rests on market failure. If markets fail to allocate resources efficiently, then there may be a role for collective action via government to try to improve efficiency.
Is there a market failure here that needs to be addressed? (I can think of two...)
Monday, October 6, 2008
Credit Crisis Explained
Friday, October 3, 2008
Short Sales
For today, I'll say this. Patrick Byrne and I agree on at least one thing: Short-selling is a good thing. Now, Byrne is a well known critic of naked shorting, but he was clear to state in his talk that he's fine with short-selling as long as the person doing the short does so on a "pre-borrow" basis. This means that the person who shorts the stock has to arrange to actually borrow the share prior to the short.
So for today let's focus on what short-selling is, and why it's a good thing.
What is it? Let's start by looking at a graphic:
Take a look at Amazon between 1998 and 2001. That's the period of the so-called dot-com-bubble. Technology stocks went way up, and then they went way back down.
Now suppose you were a super-smart market analyst, and you knew that the 1999 Amazon market prices were too high. How could you profit from this knowledge? The answer is that you could short the stock. To do this, you follow these steps:
1. Find somebody who currently owns a share of Amazon.
2. Politely ask if you can borrown their share.
3. Sell that share in the market. If, for example, you sold that share on April 16, 1999, you'd have received $95 cash from selling that share.
4. Wait.
5. Buy the share back at a later date, when (hopefully) the share price has fallen. If you bought the share on October 12, 2001, you'd have paid $8.
6. Return the share to the person you borrowed it from.
7. Pat yourself on the back --- you just made $87.
So that's what short-selling is: It's a way for people to profit when shares prices go down.
It often strikes people as odd that investors can profit when shares fall. Don't we all want share prices to rise? The answer is that if we hold stock, then we profit when shares rise in value. So in that sense we want share prices to rise.
But more generally, we want prices to be "right". That is, we want share prices to reflect the actual value (that is, net present value of cash flows) to be captured by the firm's shareholders. The reason is that people make decisions about what to do based on what prices are. And if the prices are wrong, the what-to-do decisions will be wrong.
Here's an example. In the summer of 1998, I was an assistant professor at the Kellogg School of Management at Northwestern. It's one of the world's top management schools, so an MBA from Kellogg is a really valuable stamp to have on your resume. But here's what happened that summer. First-year MBA students went away to their summer internships in Silicon Valley... and then didn't want to come back. We started geting phone calls from students --- and not a few such calls --- asking if they could defer their second year.
The reason? Their dot-com internship employers were offering them hundreds of thousands of dollars to stay. Those salary offers were way in excess of what our graduates were being offered only 18 months prior. And the students were being offered these huge salaries to do marketing and business development for business with no earnings.
Where was all the money coming from? From firms that had either gone public or were hoping to go public. Because of the dot-com bubble, businesses with not-very-good prospects were selling shares and getting huge cash infusions. And using the cash to buy first-year MBAs out of returning to school.
Do I fault the students who didn't return for school? Of course not --- they're just responding to the price signals that the labor market is sending them. Ordinarily, if a worker is offered a huge salary to do some work, it's because the work to be done is valuable. But here, labor-market price signals were wrong because the financial-market price signals were wrong. The financial market was rewarding entrepreneurs with not-very-good business models, and so the entrepreneurs were rewarding employees to do not-very-valuable work.
So, to summarize this chain: Financial-market prices affect choices in labor (and other) markets. To get the right people in the right jobs, we need financial-market prices to reflect the actual value that firms will create. This is why bubbles are a bad thing. (And think here about all the bad decisions that have been made because of the housing bubble --- it's the root cause of most of our current troubles...)
So how do we pop a bubble? In order to get a bubble popped, we need to provide incentives for the popper to pop it. That is, we need to have a way for someone to profit by making stock prices go down. That's what short-selling does, and that's why it's a good thing.
If the Bailout is the Solution, What's the Problem?
Huh? The TED spread is an obscure difference between two obscure interest rates. So let's explain what it is and why you should care. The TED spread is the difference between the three-month LIBOR interest rate and the three-month T-bill rate. The LIBOR rate is a market-determined interest rate on bank-to-bank loans. It's the answer to the question of "What interest rate will I get if I'm a bank and I loan money (for 3 months) to another bank?" The three-month T-bill rate is the answer to the question of "What interest rate will I get if I loan money (for 3 months) to the US Federal Government?"
The TED spread is the difference between these interest rates. Money lent to the US government is safe (historically). Money lent to banks might not be --- the bank could fail. The difference in these rates tells you about market perceptions of the risks of lending to a bank.
The TED spread is usually less than half a percent. Banks are seen as safe, so banks can easily borrow money. This is a good thing, because the role of banks in our economy is to get money from lenders to borrowers. It's unusual that the TED spread gets much above 1.5%. As I type this, the TED spread is 3.34%. That's really high, and it means people are afraid to lend money to banks. People are thinking "Gee, even though the LIBOR rate is a lot higher than the T-bill rate, I'm better off going with the safe option."
You can see what the TED spread is by clicking here.
If lenders are afraid to give money to banks, then banks have a harder time lending money to everyday people. This could make it harder to get a mortgage, harder to get a student loan, harder to get a credit card, harder for entrepreneurs to keep small businesses going. How much harder? It's hard to say. But this is the risk we face unless we can get the TED spread down.
It's been rightly pointed out that regular people are still able to get credit. So why all the alarm bells? The reason is that short-term disruptions in the supply of a good usually aren't noticed by consumers. Firms usually keep enough inventory on hand to be able to cover short-term supply issues. As an example, consider what happens when one of the North Salt Lake oil refineries has a technical problem (say, a pipe explodes). This reduces the supply of gasoline available, but we consumers hardly notice. The reason is that refiners keep a stock of inventory on hand just in case. During a refinery disruption, refiners draw down inventory, keep the supply out there, and motorists aren't greatly affected.
Same for the supply of money available to be lent by banks. Banks keep extra cash around just in case they have some short-run supply issues. So, a short-run TED spike is probably as bad for borrowers as a short-run refinery closure is for drivers.
But now suppose the refinery is going to stay closed for a year. Or two refineries close. Or three. Inventory isn't big enough to compensate, and we'd see gas prices rise. Same with financial markets. If the supply disruption lasts for too long, then we probably will see a larger impact on main-street lending.
This is not to say that Monday's package was a panacea. It wasn't clear exactly how much that was going to help. But you'll know when this crisis is over when the TED spread comes down.
It's also important to note that the TED spread isn't our only economic problem. Whoever wins this election will have a lot of hard decisions to make. The current Congressional negotiations aren't intended to solve all problems; they are just intended to get money flowing to banks again.
So, keep an eye on the TED spread.
About This Blog
I try to avoid having a partisan agenda, but when a politician is wrong about basic economics, I'll try to say so. I don't consult for banks or oil companies or interest groups or political parties. I'm paid by the University of Utah. So, I'm a public servant, but one who doesn't have to run for re-election. (Plus I have tenure, so I could even make my boss at the U mad if I felt like it.)
I'm also going to try to focus on Utah issues. There are a lot of other great econ blogs out there, and so Utah-related stuff is my comparative advantage.